Political Order andPolitical Decay is the second volume in Francis Fukyama’s effort to account
for the nature and functioning of political systems (for my review of the first
volume, see
here). Despite the subtitle, it is less a history of modern political order
than an attempt to theorize why political institutions work and don’t work.
Fukuyama posits three dimensions of political order: the strength of the state,
the rule, and the accountability of government to the governed. Three major
categories of social influences shape these dimensions and the interactions
among them. These are economic growth, social mobilization, and political ideas
and legitimacy.
Behind the growth of the state lies a characteristic of
human nature, the tendency of human beings to cooperate based on kinship and
reciprocity. The evolution of political order entails moving away from service
to oneself and one’s own, from patrimonial government to impersonal systems of
authority. Viewing political progress in
this way places Fukuyama within the tradition of Max Weber: bureaucracy does
not have the negative implications that it does in much common usage, but is a
rational and goal-directed organization of behavior. Fukuyama’s contributions to this Weberian
perspective might lie in his attention to the dimension of accountability, of
the explicit recognition that bureaucracies can be evaluated by how well they
serve some set of public interests, and in his observation that states and
their bureaucracies can only be accountable to the extent that they are subject
to laws as well as carry out laws.
Fukuyama sees political order as a balance among his three
dimensions. In the first volume, he described Chinese imperial governance as an
early well-developed state that ruled by law but that was not itself under the
law, and in this second book he traces that heritage to the challenges of
modern China, which retains a strong state, but is not yet fully accountable to
its population. Nevertheless, China
recovered from the colonial challenge of the West because it retained an ingrained
political order. Other Asian nations that originally emerged under Chinese
influence were also fairly successful in responding to Western pressures,
especially Japan, which was able to integrate a strong state with political
influences from Europe and America. By contrast, the nations of Africa have
been notably unsuccessful because no cohesive state existed in them before the
Europeans disrupted the Africans’ largely tribal organizations without creating
deep-rooted and widely-accepted patterns of authority. Western colonialism was
generally more successful in the Americas, especially where settler populations
largely replaced pre-existing ones. The Americas, however, had varying
outcomes, in Fukuyama’s view because their histories resulted from combinations
of different European legacies, unique geographical and social contexts, and
decisions of policy-makers.
Fukuyama is less appreciative of the early political history
of the United States than are many other historical commentators. He views the
extension of male suffrage in this country in the nineteenth century as the
growth of democratic accountability before the emergence of a strong central
state, producing clientelism. This perspective leads him to an enthusiastic appraisal
of Progressive Era reforms, such as the civil service and unaccountable federal
bureaucracies, which he presents as professionally dedicated to national-well
being. He sees the governmental stalemates of the present as the consequence of
the recapture of government by a multitude of special interests, creating a “vetocracy”
of pressure groups that push the bureaucracies in different directions and
prevent a strong, professionalized government from operating autonomously.
I was less impressed with this second book than with the
first. This one does incorporate a wide range of information, but sometimes too
much, so that it seems like Fukuyama was trying to work in whatever he happened
to be reading at the time of writing. While the three dimensions of political
order did offer a useful way of conceptualizing at the most abstract level, there
were so many elements within the three kinds of influences that the schema
often appeared to explain everything and nothing. When discussing why Costa
Rica has been a successful nation since the middle of the twentieth century and
Argentina has been much less successful, for example, Fukuyama is left telling
us that Costa Rican politicians made good decisions and those of Argentina bad
ones. That may well be so, but it is not much of an explanation.
The latter-day Progressivism embraced by the author ignores
the New Class argument that self-controlling state bureaucracies do not necessarily
serve some objective pubic good, but are themselves political actors. Even when agency officials do not seek to
benefit their own kin and allies, the dedication to organizational interests
often forms a tribal commitment. In his enthusiasm for the autonomous,
non-patrimonial state, Fukuyama overlooks the point that governments and
government agencies are not just more or less accountable to their populations:
the authorities are self-promoting parts of the population. They may be all the more dangerous precisely because
they do not see their agencies as pursuing narrow self-interest, but as
enlightened rulers who have the expertise to decide what is good for everyone. When
bureaucratic progressivism produces sections of the population who can set
themselves up as experts on how everyone should live and what everyone should
think “accountability” shifts its
meaning from representatives being accountable to an electorate to social
technicians obtaining public assent to the technicians’ designs for a shared
future.
I am not sure, then, that the impasses in US political life
today are necessarily due to a “vetocracy” that impedes the salubrious
decision-making of an active central government. Rather, I think it is because a highly
centralized American state has brought together groups within our population
who have vastly different and even opposing ideas about what would constitute
the general good on the major issues of the day. If autonomous agencies would
have the power to make the decisions, the bureaucratic power would not make
those decisions any less partisan.
Pliz Check Our Products N Get Big BIg BONUS !!! sabungayam WA : +62812-2222-995 | BBM : BOLAVITA / D8C363CA
ReplyDelete